REDISTRIBUTION,
INNOVATION,
COMBATTING
CLIMATE CHANGE:
THREE MAJOR
FISCAL CHALLENGES
IN THE AFTERMATH
OF THE PANDEMIC
Summary
February 2022
CP
prélèvements
obligatoires
conseil des
2
Summary - Council of Mandatory Contributions
g
NOTICE
This document is intended to facilitate the reading and use of the
report by the Council of Mandatory Contributions.
Both the general report and the special reports are made public
and can be viewed on the website www.ccomptes.fr/CPO.
Only the text of the report is binding on the Council of Mandatory
Contributions.
3
Summary - Council of Mandatory Contributions
Contents
Introduction
4
1
Clarifying the debate on the redistributive effects
. . . . . . . . .
of compulsory levies
. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
5
2
Improving the effectiveness of innovation taxation
. . . . . . . .
9
3
Fostering consent to energy taxation
. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
17
Conclusion .
23
4
Summary - Council of Mandatory Contributions
Introduction
This report attempts to draw the first fiscal lessons from a crisis that
has not yet come to an end. The Covid-19 pandemic, which broke out
in China at the end of 2019 before spreading to the rest of the world,
continues to take its toll on economies and societies. Although it is on
its way out, this crisis will leave deep marks on the global economy.
Firstly, the scale of the budgetary efforts made to cushion the effects
has led to an unprecedented increase in public debt. In addition,
the disorganisation of production resulting from the pandemic has led
to supply shortages, which have severely constrained supply in certain
sectors (electronics, automotive, etc.), contributing to the resurgence
of inflation. Lastly, the crisis has accelerated economic and societal
changes, some of which had been under way for several years but were
not yet very visible: a turning point in the awareness of environmental
challenges, the rise of remote work and the return of concerns about
the location of productive activities, particularly when they contribute
to establishing or regaining economic sovereignty.
In this context, tax policy, without being exclusive of other instruments
such as public expenditure or regulation, will play a decisive role in the
years to come. In this report, the Council of Mandatory Contributions
(
Conseil des prélèvements obligatoires
– CPO) has chosen to focus
on
three challenges that it considers crucial in the context of
exiting the crisis: social and territorial inequalities, innovation
and environment
. The common thread among the three subjects
selected by the CPO is that they are directly in the field of action of
fiscal policies: taxation is a key instrument of redistribution, whether
in terms of income or wealth; innovation is the subject of numerous
tax incentives, the most important of which is the research tax credit,
a tax expenditure whose burden to the central government budget
amounts to over €6bn, nearly twice the budget of the National Centre
for Scientific Research (CNRS); lastly, taxation is at the heart of
policies aimed at limiting climate change, by implementing a system
of incentives designed to limit carbon emissions and encourage the
use of alternative energy sources.
5
Summary - Council of Mandatory Contributions
Clarifying the debate
on the redistributive effects
of compulsory levies
1
1
Redistribution: a key function
of government finances
Inequality has become a major topic
of public debate in recent decades.
All opinion polls confirm the rise
in concerns over the distribution
of income and wealth. However,
the inequalities that French people
feel today do not just concern
income or wealth. They are increas-
ingly encompassing the country:
the metropolisation movement that
has characterised recent decades
have also led to a decline in the
attractiveness of other parts of the
country, in both rural and suburban
areas, sometimes fuelling a feeling
of relegation. To deal with this
development, the public authorities
have tools for taking action.
Public expenditure and revenue
have redistributive properties: they
modify the primary distribution of
income and wealth, depending on
Key
Category
0.0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
Share
Levies on production
and consumption
Income and wealth tax
Social security contributions
Graph 1: Levies in extended primary income,
by twentieth of living standard
Note: the wealthiest 5% contribute on average 30% of their pre-transfer income under
income and wealth taxes and 18% under social security contributions.
Sources: 2018 distributed national accounts (ERFS, Ines-Omar, SNDS, DADS, Fidéli).
1
This chapter is based in particular on the special report "Compulsory levies in respect of
redistribution challenges", written for the CPO by Mathias André, director at INSEE. It is available
particulier-redistribution.pdf
6
Summary - Council of Mandatory Contributions
Clarifying the debate on the redistributive
effects of taxes
whether they are designed to do so
or whether, without being assigned
a
redistributive
objective,
they
nevertheless affect households in
different ways. Statistical work such
as the work to establish "distributed
national accounts" provides a basis
for studying the characteristics of
this redistributive function.
Overall proportional
compulsory levies
The study of distributed national
accounts shows that compulsory
levies only play a marginal role in
reducing inequality in France. Viewed
as a whole, the French compulsory
levies system is proportional overall,
as shown in the graph below.
The redistribution implemented
by the tax and social system
as a whole benefits two thirds
of households
Considered as a whole, the redistri-
bution implemented by the tax and
social system results in two thirds
of households benefiting from it.
This analysis highlights the extent
of the redistribution implemented
by public budgets. As such, we can
see that net transfers from public
budgets are positive for two thirds
Transfers
Category
Breakdown before and after transfers, for 2018
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
Individual in kind social
payments
Monetary social benefits
Net national revenue before
transfers
Levies on production
and consumption
Collective expenditure and
consumption of fixed capital
of which pensions
Income and wealth tax
Social security contributions
Euros per CU
2e+05
1e+05
0e+00
Graph 2: Extended redistribution by twentieth of living standard
Note: the wealthiest 5% contribute on average 30% of their pre-transfer income under
income and wealth taxes and 18% under social security contributions.
Sources: 2018 distributed national accounts (ERFS, Ines-Omar, SNDS, DADS, Fidéli)
7
Summary - Council of Mandatory Contributions
of households. Moreover, redistri-
bution has a very substantial impact
in terms of reducing inequalities:
while the average extended primary
income of the wealthiest 10% of indi-
viduals is 13 times higher than that of
the poorest 10%, this ratio is reduced
to 7 in terms of the usual standard
of living (disposable income) and to
3 in terms of the extended standard
of living (including transfers in kind
and collective expenditure).
Ultimately, an analysis of redistribu-
tion restricted to public expenditure
or public revenue alone is limited in
scope. It is in any case less signifi-
cant than an analysis of all public
transfers,
including
expenditure
and revenue.
Redistribution and the
territories: the Paris region
is a major contributor
to transfers
A territorial approach to redistri-
bution shows that redistribution
tends
to
homogenise
average
incomes across territories after
transfers, primarily to the benefit of
cities in urban areas with between
20,000 and 200,000 inhabitants.
Rural cities are only mild benefi-
ciaries of redistribution. Ultimately,
the urban area of Paris is the only
net contributor to the extended
redistribution.
Graph 3: Extended redistribution by size of urban unit
Transfers
Category
Breakdown before and after transfers, for 2018
1 Rural cities
2. < 20,000 inhab.
3. 20 - 20,000 inhab.
4. > 20,000 inhab.
5. Paris
Individual in kind social
payments
Monetary social benefits
Net national revenue before
transfers
Levies on production
and consumption
Collective expenditure and
consumption of fixed capital
of which pensions
Income and wealth tax
Social security contributions
Euros per CU
-30,000
30,000
60,000
0
Note: Consumption of fixed capital (CCF) measures the investments necessary to
reconstitute capital (in this case, public assets).
Sources: 2018 distributed national accounts (ERFS, Ines-Omar, SNDS, DADS, Fidéli)
8
Summary - Council of Mandatory Contributions
Clarifying the debate on the redistributive
effects of taxes
Informing the democratic
debate on the redistributive
role of public budgets
It is not the CPO's role to issue audit
recommendations on the correct
level of redistribution implemented
by public budgets, which is a policy
choice. Conversely, the CPO's mission
is to shed light on the conditions
under which public choices are
made concerning the redistribution
of compulsory levies.
This is why the guidelines it has
adopted aim to improve the quality
of the available information on the
distribution of levies and, above
all, to better inform decisions on
redistribution choices by improving
knowledge of the various instru-
ments' redistributive impact.
Accordingly, the CPO makes the
following audit recommendations:
• Audit recommendation 1:
sup-
plement the tax data available
to researchers, particularly with
regard to the taxation of wealth
and inheritance.
• Audit recommendation 2:
make
the redistribution indicators of
the social and fiscal system as
a whole available to Parliament
on a regular basis, in order to
provide an objective basis for the
debate on redistribution and the
means to advance it; the CPO will
contribute to this information
by periodically publishing infor-
mation on the redistribution of
public budgets.
9
Summary - Council of Mandatory Contributions
Improving the effectiveness
of innovation taxation
2
2
Innovation is undoubtedly one of the
main economic challenges as we exit
the crisis. According to the INSEE,
it refers to the introduction onto the
market of a new product or process,
or one that is significantly improved
compared to those previously devel-
oped. This concept is distinguished
from
research
and
development
(R&D) by the requirement of being
aligned with a market and by the
existence of innovations in use that
are not purely scientific and technical.
Due to the positive externalities
that characterise innovative activi-
ties – where the return to society is
greater than the private return to
the originator –, governments seek
to implement public policies to sup-
port and accelerate them. Taxation
is one of the instruments to achieve
this: for example, Germany adopted
a research tax credit at a federal level
in November 2019, joining France
and several other European coun-
tries that had already implemented
this type of system. The pandemic
has reinforced this trend, emphasis-
ing the need to preserve an effective
innovation ecosystem capable of
rapidly fostering the emergence
of
innovations
meeting
societal
needs that are sometimes diffi
cult
to anticipate. In this context, the key
question is how to improve both the
effectiveness and effi
ciency of inno-
vation taxation in France.
Graph 4: Domestic R&D expenditure in OECD countries in 2019 (as % of GDP)
Mexico
Colombia
Chile
Latvia
Slovakia
Lithuania
Turkey
Luxembourg
Ireland
Spain
Greece
Poland
Portugal
New Zealand
Italy
Hungary
Canada
Estonia
United Kingdom
Australia
Czech Republic
Slovenia
Norway
Netherlands
France
Iceland
OECD
Finland
Denmark
United States
Austria
Belgium
Switzerland
Germany
Japan
Sweden
Korea
Israel
0.3
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
0.3
0.4
0.6
0.8
1.0
1.1
1.1
1.2
1.3
1.3
1.3
1.4
1.4
1.5
1.5
1.6
1.6
1.8
1.8
1.9
2.1
2.2
2.2
2.2
2.3
2.5
2.8
2.9
3.1
3.1
3.2
3.2
3.2
3.2
3.4
4.6
4.9
Source: OECD, 2021, Gross Domestic Expenditure on R&D (indicator)
2
This chapter draws in particular on the special report "Innovation taxation: improving the
effectiveness of existing systems, continuing their assessment", written for the CPO by Antoine
Comte-Bellot, auditor at the Court of Accounts, and Louis de Crevoisier, finance inspector.
02/20220209-rapport-particulier-fiscalite-innovation.pdf
10
Summary - Council of Mandatory Contributions
Improving the effectiveness
of innovation taxation
High-level research
but a persistently weak
innovation system
According to OECD data, France
spent 2.2% of its gross domestic
product (GDP) on R&D in 2019,
giving domestic expenditure on
research and development (GERD)
of €53.2bn, putting it in 13th place
in the OECD and above the EU-27
average (2.12%).
This research effort is reflected in
an innovation activity that ranks
France slightly above the European
average in this area, as shown by
the European Innovation Score-
board for 2021 published by the
European Commission. Although
France is one of the "strong innova-
tors", it is behind the four European
"innovation
leaders"
(Sweden,
Finland, Denmark and Belgium) and
behind five other countries in the
same category (the Netherlands,
Germany,
Luxembourg,
Austria
and Estonia).
However, the French innovation
system is characterised by per-
sistent
weaknesses,
particularly
in terms of non-R&D innovation
expenditure, links between research
Graph 5: Performance of EU Member States' innovation systems
EMERGING INNOVATORS
MODERATE INNOVATORS
STRONG INNOVATORS
INNOVATION LEADERS
2014
2020
Reading note: The dotted lines indicate the threshold values between the performance
groups, with the threshold values of 70%, 100% and 125% adjusted upwards to reflect
the increase in EU performance between 2014 and 2021.
Source: "European Innovation Scoreboard, Main Report", June 2021, p. 16
11
Summary - Council of Mandatory Contributions
and industry and patent production
in certain technology sectors.
In this respect, in terms of the number
of triadic patents
3
per million inhabit-
ants, France fell from 6th place in
1995 to 10th place in 1999, before
stabilising until 2009, then falling
again to 15th place in 2015.
These difficulties reflect French
industry's declining share of GDP
4
,
inadequacy of technology innova-
tions in all sectors and systemic
weakness in the mechanisms for
promoting public research, which
the reforms of the last decade have
not managed to erase.
Although there are
many tax incentives for
research and innovation,
their sharply rising cost
for government finances
is concentrated on the
research tax credit (CIR)
Tax incentives' share of innovation
support has significantly increased
over the last two decades. A 2016
France
Stratégie
report
5
high-
lighted that it had risen from 16.5%
3
Triadic patent families are a set of patents filed with three main offices, namely the European
Patent Office (EPO), the Japanese Patent Office (JPO) and the United States Patent and
Trademark Office (USPTO). Triadic patent family counts are attributed to the country of
residence of the inventor and refer to the date on which the patent was first registered.
This indicator is stated by volume (source: OECD).
4
Industry's share of French GDP (17.1% in 2019 according to the World Bank definition) is lower
than in Germany (26.2%), the US (18.2%) and the OECD average (22.4%).
Table 1: Change in the resources of central government and its operators
to foster innovation by financing method
Modalities
2000
Share in %
2015
Share in %
Change (%)
Tax
incentives
584
16.5
6,341
74.2
+ 810
Subsidies
2,854
80.9
1,636
19.2
- 52
Loans
0
0.0
198
2.3
0
Shareholdings
91
2.6
376
4.4
+ 246
Total
3,529 .3
100 .0
8,551
100 .0
+ 103
Source: CNEPI, 2015
12
Summary - Council of Mandatory Contributions
Improving the effectiveness
of innovation taxation
of total innovation support in 2000
to 74.5% in 2015. This share has
since stabilised.
This development is the result of
both economic and legal consid-
erations – the search for greater
neutrality in innovation support
schemes to comply with the central
government aid system and avoid
interfering with the functioning of
the market – and budgetary consid-
erations – tax credits having been
subject to less restrictive standards
in the preparation of the central
government budget than those
that apply to expenditure trends.
The overview of tax incentives
leads us to estimate their amount
at nearly €7.4bn in 2019. The CIR
represents 86% of this amount.
However, the expenditure taken
into account for the CIR does not
specifically
support
innovation
expenditure, concerning instead the
broader set of beneficiary compa-
nies' research expenditure. Support
more targeted at innovation (such
as the Young Innovative Businesses
Graph 6: Direct and indirect public funding of business R&D
(as % of GDP)
0.50
0.45
0.40
0.35
0.30
0.25
0.20
0.15
0.10
0.05
0.00
Sub-national fiscal support for GERD
Tax incentive for GERD
Direct funding of GERD
Note: * Data on fiscal support not available; ** Data on sub-national fiscal support
not available.
Source: OECD R&D Tax Incentive Database, March 2021; CPO calculations
5
CNEPI and France Stratégie, 2016, "Fifteen years of innovation policies in France".
13
Summary - Council of Mandatory Contributions
(
Jeunes entreprises innovantes
– JEI)
scheme) represents much smaller
amounts.
Although France is not the only coun-
try to use tax incentives to support
innovation, it has the highest amounts
of incentives (R&D tax incentives
represent 0.29% of GDP, compared
with an OECD average of 0.1%).
Assessments that indicate
the need for an adaptation
of tax incentives for R&D
and innovation
The need to adapt tax incentives
for innovation is based both on
assessments of these tax measures
and efforts already made to reduce
corporate taxation.
Effectiveness of the CIR can still
be improved
Assessments of the CIR conducted
under the guidance of the National
Commission for the Evaluation of
Innovation Policies (CNEPI) con-
clude that the overall effectiveness
of the system is limited. Firstly,
they highlight
6
some positive effects
of the system. As such, the CIR
prompts businesses to increase
their level of R&D expenditure by
an amount roughly equivalent to
the
additional
tax
expenditure,
i.e. a knock-on effect of around 1.
Graph 7: R&D conducted abroad by foreign subsidiaries of US groups,
by region and by selected countries (in millions of US dollars 2010)
2000
2,000
4,000
6,000
8,000
10,000
12,000
14,000
16,000
18,000
2005
2010
2015
China
United
Kingdom
Rest
of Asia
Germany
Least
developed
countries
Rest
of Europe
France
Latin
America
Japan
Source: EU Industrial R&D Investment Scoreboard, NEOMA-BS 2021 study
6
CNEPI, 2019, "The impact of the research tax credit".
14
Summary - Council of Mandatory Contributions
Improving the effectiveness
of innovation taxation
However, empirical studies con-
ducted by the OECD indicate that
this knock-on effect is greater for
small and medium-sized enterprises
(SMEs) than for large groups
7
.
According to these same assess-
ments
8
, the 2008 reform of the CIR
had positive effects on innovation
variables (such as the employ-
ment of engineers and the filing
of patents) and activity variables
(such as an increase in investment
or revenue) that only concern SMEs.
Conversely, the available data show
that the effects of the CIR have not
been suffi
cient to reverse France's
loss of attractiveness as a location
for foreign multinationals' R&D
9
.
Similarly, while
French
multina-
tionals have increased their R&D
expenditure
over
the
last
two
decades, they have done so at
a slower pace than the major OECD
countries.
In short, although they need to be
supplemented, the existing assess-
ments highlight the fact that the
effectiveness of the CIR can still be
improved.
7
OECD, 2020, "How effective are tax incentives for R&D? New evidence from the OECD
microBeRD project": the knock-on effect of tax credits for R&D expenditure is 0.4 for large
businesses, 1 for medium-sized businesses and 1.4 for small businesses.
8
L. Bach et al., 2021, "The impact of the research tax credit on the economic performance of
businesses", IPP Report no. 33.
9
S. Lhuillery et al. (2021) "French companies' R&D and the CIR", NEOMA BS workpaper.
Graph 7: Change in amounts spent on R&D by groups that invest the most in R&D,
by country (base 100 in 2005)
France
Sweden
Germany
Switzerland
Japan
United Kingdom
Netherlands
United States
South Korea
World
Source: EU Industrial R&D Investment Scoreboard, NEOMA-BS 2021 study
15
Summary - Council of Mandatory Contributions
The uncertain effectiveness of
other tax measures to support
innovation
With the exception of the CIR,
which was assessed in two phases
over five years by the National
Commission for the Evaluation of
Innovation Policies (CNEPI) using
microeconometric methods, recent
assessments of tax incentives for
innovation remain limited. Therefore:
• reduced taxation of income from
certain industrial property assets:
the French
"patent box" scheme
has
still
not
been
extensively
assessed,
despite
its
significant
amount (€586m in 2019) and the
fact that it is the second largest
tax
incentive
for
innovation
in
France by volume. Given that this
tax system was revised in 2019,
its assessment should be a priority.
As was the case with the CIR, the
assessment should focus on its
additional character, as well as
its direct impact on innovation,
through the quantity and quality of
the patents concerned;
• the JEI scheme
: assessments of
the JEI tax scheme have focused
on its effect on R&D employment,
but have not sought to measure its
impact on innovation;
• the exceptional deduction in favour
of SME investment in robotics and
digitisation
: the tax expenditure
assessment programme presented
in the PLF for 2020 provided for
the assessment in 2020 of the
exceptional deduction in favour of
SME investment in robotics and
industrial digitisation. This was not
the case.
Reviewing tax incentives
for innovation in terms
of efficiency, assessment
and steering
The review of fiscal instruments
related to support for R&D and
innovation should take into account
the need to step up technological
innovation across all sectors of the
economy to contend with climate
change and digital transformation.
The OECD estimates that $6.9 trillion
per year in green investment will
be needed worldwide over the next
15 years, a 10% increase on current
infrastructure
investment
flows.
In 2018, the European Commission
estimated that between €175bn and
€290bn per year would be needed
over
the
2030-2050
period
in
Europe to achieve carbon neutrality
by 2050. The report by France's
Ministry for Ecological Transition on
the national low-carbon strategy in
2020 put the additional investment
cost to be borne at nearly 2.5% of
GDP for all sectors combined.
In addition to this effort, the chal-
lenges of digital transformation
need to be taken into account. In
this respect, the degree of digiti-
sation of French businesses
10
is
comparable to that observed in
16
Summary - Council of Mandatory Contributions
Improving the effectiveness
of innovation taxation
Europe, both in terms of so-called
mature
digital
tools
(manage-
ment software, automated invoice
processing) and emerging technol-
ogies (cloud computing, mass data,
artificial intelligence).
Accordingly, the CPO presents the
following audit recommendations:
• Recommendation 3
: Include the
reform of the CIR and tax incentives
to support innovation in an overall
review of ways to strengthen the
innovation efforts of French busi-
nesses to contend with the dual
ecological and digital revolution.
• Recommendation 4
: Initiate a
reduction in the current cap on
the CIR.
The CPO favours a stricter progres-
sive cap on the CIR for the following
reasons: the context of the reduction
in the nominal rate of corporation
tax, which is already reducing the
intensity of this tax incentive; the
fact that all OECD countries that
have introduced a CIR have opted for
a cap that is much lower than the one
in effect in France (€4m in Germany
for example); the concern to give
priority to the stability of incen-
tives and to not alter a system that
remains, despite its limited effec-
tiveness, a tax attractiveness factor
for France. This scenario should be
accompanied by an adaptation of the
rules on central government aid, in
particular EU Regulation 1407-2013,
known as the de minimis regula-
tion
11
, to enable all stakeholders to
participate in the research and inno-
vation effort.
• Recommendation 5
: Extend the
JEI scheme to eligible expenses
for
the
innovation
tax
credit
(
crédit d’impôt innovation
– CII),
by eliminating the tax expenditure
associated with this scheme.
• Recommendation 6
: Integrate tax
incentives into the overall manage-
ment of innovation policy by setting
up a tool for monitoring public aid
for innovation and by using the Data
Hub project of the Directorate Gen-
eral for Enterprise (DGE) for central
government aid.
• Recommendation 7
: Ensure sys-
tematic assessment of the main
tax incentives for innovation (CIR,
reduced rate of taxation on income
from
certain
industrial
property
assets, JEI, exceptional deduction
for SME investment in robotics)
at intervals to be defined, based on
the
capital
taxation
assessment
model, which since 2018 has been
entrusted to a specialised commit-
tee attached to France Stratégie.
10
See Trésor Éco note no.271 – November 2020 – Digitisation of French businesses.
11
This European regulation limits to €200,000 over a three-year period public aid that is paid to
businesses and is not subject to prior authorisation by the European Commission. It is in force
until 31 December 2023.
17
Summary - Council of Mandatory Contributions
Fostering consent
to energy taxation
12
3
Ecology taxation includes all taxes
and charges based on a pollutant
or, more generally, on a product or
service that damages the environ-
ment. As such, it applies to actions
that
generate
environmental
damage: climate change, pollution,
consumption of scarce resources,
waste, etc. By making them more
expensive, it helps to limit pollu-
tion and environmental damage
and therefore represents a way
to modify the behaviour of stake-
holders, in accordance with the
"polluter pays" principle.
Few environmental policy instru-
ments seem to attract as much
resistance today as environmental
taxation. The two most unusual
social movements – and the most
costly for government finances –
of the 2010 decade in France,
namely the Red Caps in 2013 and
the Yellow Vests in 2018, mobilised
unprecedented forms of protest
with the aim of blocking environ-
mental taxes, the ecotax for heavy
goods vehicles in the former case
and the taxes that enter into the
price of fuel at the pump in the
latter, although these were not the
only reasons for these movements.
This lack of acceptance of energy
taxes is all the more interesting to
observe because it contradicts the
main tool promoted by economists
to combat greenhouse gas emis-
sions: the price of carbon, of which
the carbon tax is one of the two
main forms, along with emissions
quota trading schemes. This para-
doxical situation prompted the CPO,
without returning to the conclu-
sions of its September 2019 report
entitled
Environmental taxation and
the climate change challenge
, which
it still considers relevant, to look at
ways of making it more acceptable
to tax payers.
Three hurdles to the
acceptance of ecology
taxation in France
The freeze on the carbon component
of domestic consumption taxes
at
its
2018
level
(€44.6/tCO
2
)
since the Yellow Vests movement
is a major setback to the public
authorities' ambitions for incentive-
based energy taxation. Three years
after this freeze decision, several
blocking factors have been clearly
identified and explain why 2022 is
ultimately not the year of a switch
12
This chapter is based on the special report "Consent to environmental taxation" written for
the CPO by Jonas Anne-Braun, finance inspector, and Tristan Guesdon, intern, student at the
ENS (Paris), as well as on elements from an article, taken from this special report and written by
the same authors, entitled "Can energy taxation become acceptable?", no. 176, OFCE Review,
February 2022.
files/2022-02/20220209-rapport-particulier-consentement-fiscalite-environnementale.pdf
176OFCE.pdf.
18
Summary - Council of Mandatory Contributions
Fostering consent to energy taxation
to a carbon tax of €86.2/tCO
2
as
planned in the 2018 Budget Act
13
.
The diffi
culties surrounding the
acceptance of environmental taxa-
tion have their roots in our country's
long history, and in particular
the
traditional unpopularity of indi-
rect taxes and duties
, among which
excise duties on energy are now in
second place after VAT. An interna-
tional comparison shows that rather
than being an isolated case, this
situation is instead the expression
of the long-standing unpopularity
of energy taxation shared through-
out the world.
A
second
well-identified
reason
for blocking an increase in energy
taxation is the
socio-spatial differ-
entiation of its impacts
. As such,
household location is usually put
forward as the main explanation
for the inconsistency in energy's
share of household budgets due to
its impact on transport times and
heating methods.
The analysis of the impact of place
of residence combined with the
analysis of income level has led
some
authors to
highlight the
existence of "energy prisoners",
a category of tax payers who are
Graph 9: Bills, energy effort rate and energy tax effort rate according
to household area of residence
20.0
effort rate as % of total household income
Housing bill incl. tax
Transport bill incl. tax
Residential area
Paris urban unit
(17%)
Urban unit with
200,000 to 1,999,999
inhabitants (25%)
Urban unit with
20,000 to 200,000
inhabitants (19%)
Urban unit with
fewer than 20,000
inhabitants (18%)
Rural city
(22%)
bills, in €
Average total energy effort rate
Energy taxation effort rate (including VAT)
4.5
3.9
3.5
3.3
2.1
18.0
16.0
14.0
12.0
10.0
8.0
6.0
4.8
7.1
7.7
8.3
9.4
4.0
2.0
0.0
Source: CPO (2019) based on the Promotheus model (MTES-CGDD,
updated 2017, January 2019 prices and legislation, 2018 income).
13
The threshold to cross was very high: the increase was €14.1 per tonne in 2018 followed by an
annual increase of €10.1 per tonne until 2022. The ambition to reach the €100 threshold in 2030
became more credible. In addition, there was a diesel-petrol catch-up. However, the impact assess-
ment did not base the increase in the carbon trajectory on a strengthening of the climate objectives,
but rather on a performance objective. The revenue surplus was put at over €15bn by 2022.
19
Summary - Council of Mandatory Contributions
highly dependent on energy, both
because of their modest social
position and their constrained resi-
dential situation. The Yellow Vests
crisis provided ample validation
for this analysis by creating polit-
ical visibility for this category of
the population, mainly comprised
of socially modest and geographi-
cally remote workers, for whom an
increase in energy taxation would
necessarily lead to an erosion of
purchasing
power,
rather
than
a reduction in the use of carbon-
based energy.
A third obstacle is the ambiguity of
the objectives pursued by environ-
mental taxation, between budgetary
performance and changing house-
hold behaviour. From the viewpoint
of tax payers' acceptance of energy
taxation, however, the dual func-
tion of an incentive tax such as
the carbon tax represents more of
a threat than an opportunity: the
accusation of a performance func-
tion can emerge very easily, and the
lack of convincing communication
on the use of the revenue generated
is likely to seriously compromise
the acceptance of the instrument by
giving substance to this accusation
and implying that the performance
function is primary.
The conditions for acceptable
energy taxation: three choices
to be made
Rather than being technical issues,
the parameters that determine the
design of energy taxation are funda-
mental policy choices that have not
always been properly highlighted
in the past. These policy choices
are essentially threefold: an energy
efficiency objective in addition to
a decarbonisation objective, the type
of allocation of environmental tax
revenues and the degree of uni-
formity of the carbon price across
sectors and products.
Increase the price of energy
overall or only the price of certain
types of energy?
The first dilemma concerns the very
nature of the energy taxation that
central governments want: should
energy
taxation
be
conceived
primarily as a tool affecting the
relative prices of energy sources to
create a switch, or also as a tool to
increase energy prices as a whole?
Sweden
offers
an
example
of
a strategy based on both a sharp
increase in the carbon tax and
the introduction of alternatives to
carbon-based energy. As a result,
it has a carbon pricing system
that is unparalleled so far. While
France set the carbon compo-
nent rate at €44.6/tCO
2
, Sweden
moved to a non-dispensation rate
of €120/tCO
2
. However, care needs
to be taken not to attribute all of
the credit for Sweden's climate
successes
to
taxation
alone:
because the public authorities were
able to make significant green invest-
ments further up the line, offering
20
Summary - Council of Mandatory Contributions
Fostering consent to energy taxation
concrete alternatives to carbon-
based consumption, the price signal
from taxation influenced consumer
choices, all the more easily because
they had access to untaxed alter-
natives. The case of the district
heating networks in which Sweden
invested hugely at the time of the
"green tax shift", and which were
promoted as alternatives to individual
heating, is a good example of this
approach
14
.
Alongside this model of taxation
aimed primarily at creating a clear
difference in price between carbon-
based and decarbonised energies,
there is a separate vision, at work in
France and in the European frame-
work of energy taxation, inspired
by the goal of
energy efficiency
.
The idea is that the role of energy
taxation is to limit the develop-
ment of economic structures overly
dependent on energy in general
and
not
just
on
carbon-based
energies,
by
promoting
energy-
efficient
production
methods.
The term energy efficiency is used
in the "energy taxation" directive
2003/87/EC, which sets legal floors
for the various energy excise duties
applied in the EU.
By
choosing
to
increase
the
carbon component according to
an ambitious trajectory without
significantly lowering other energy
taxes, France has implicitly chosen
an energy efficiency goal with an
increase in absolute prices, in addi-
tion to a decarbonisation goal that
plays on the relative prices between
energies. At first sight, this choice,
which in principle is more painful
for tax payers, may appear to be an
explanation for the failure of the
tax
.
However, its relevance seems
to remain intact for at least two
fundamental reasons:
• The first is that energy efficiency
is perhaps more than ever an
essential preparation for adapting
to a world transformed by climate
change;
• the second reason is that the
introduction of a switchover tax
between energy sources means
explicitly
designating
which
energies will be promoted by
tax cuts, at the risk of making
environmental mistakes. This is
the significance of the debates
about the ecological character
of electric cars, biofuels and even
nuclear power.
The Swedish and Icelandic experi-
ences therefore show the greater
acceptability
of
taxation
that
differentiates
between
energies,
as long as alternatives exist, even
though the objective of energy
efficiency – which is less socially
acceptable – would appear to have
the advantage of more effectively
planning
ahead
for
an
energy
uncertain future.
14
Pottier, A., 2016, How economists are heating up the planet, Seuil.
21
Summary - Council of Mandatory Contributions
Should the tax revenues from envi-
ronmental taxation be allocated to
"green" investments or to offsetting
the loss of purchasing power among
those on the lowest incomes?
International
comparisons
con-
ducted by the CPO show that
proper governance of the use (or
"recycling") of carbon tax revenues
is a condition that can significantly
improve
its
acceptance
by
tax
payers. The range of possible uses
of revenues is very wide, as shown
by the diverse foreign experiences
in this area. However, a pivotal
alternative is emerging: the choice
between
allocating
revenue
to
expenditure aimed at accelerating
the ecological transition and allo-
cating it to a mechanism to offset
losses in purchasing power, in the
case of households, or competi-
tiveness, in the case of businesses.
However, France is lagging behind
in this area since, with the excep-
tion of the energy transition special
appropriation account, which con-
stituted a variation of the first type
of recycling but was abolished on
1 January 2021, there is currently
no explicit system for recycling
energy tax revenues in France.
Differentiated or uniform carbon
taxation?
The French carbon component of
domestic consumption taxes has
many exemptions and reduced rates
depending on the type of energy
product consumed and the contrib-
uting sector, which reflects the
overall situation of energy taxation
in Europe. The role of these reduced
rates and exemptions is ambiguous,
due to their dual effect: by distancing
the carbon tax from an ideal of
uniformity, they can contribute to
a feeling of injustice and inefficiency,
but by specifically reducing the tax
burden for certain stakeholders they
can be a driver of acceptance and
reducing opposition.
Most
economists
believe
that
the low consistency in the distri-
bution of effort is an obstacle to
the acceptability of environmen-
tal taxation, in addition to being
a source of ecological inefficiency:
the uniformity of carbon prices is
implicitly set up as a standard of
justice. However, there is evidence
that not all price differences are
perceived as unfair by tax payers.
On the contrary, in certain limited
cases
and
provided
they
are
justified, the possibilities for exemp-
tions can be a help rather than
a hindrance to the acceptability
of a tax. As such, while the objec-
tive of a uniform carbon tax must
remain an objective, duly justified
adjustments can be introduced on
a transitional basis in certain cases,
in order to remove political oppo-
sition to incentive energy taxation,
thereby creating the conditions for
greater acceptability.
22
Summary - Council of Mandatory Contributions
Fostering consent to energy taxation
The conditions for
implementing an acceptable
energy tax: three drivers
Given the scale of climate change,
the question is no longer so much
the relevance of environmental tax-
ation as the forms it should take in
order to be effective and accepted
by a large majority of tax payers.
To do this, it is necessary to:
• remove some of the obstacles by
redirecting some of our environ-
mental taxation tools towards
more acceptable instruments;
• create
instruments
that
are
consistent with the socio-fiscal
system and other environmental
policy instruments. In other words,
the creation of viable alternatives
to carbon-based energy sources
and public investment in large-
scale emission reduction plans
ultimately appear to be the main
conditions for the acceptability
of
incentive
energy
taxation.
Strong energy taxation is neces-
sary, but not sufficient, condition
for reducing our greenhouse gas
emissions;
• create new instruments, adapted
to a globalised economy, notably
by supporting the introduction of
a carbon tax at the EU's borders.
Ultimately, the CPO makes the
following audit recommendations:
To remove the barriers to acceptance
of environmental taxation:
• Audit recommendation 8:
Allo-
cate environmental tax revenues
to redistributive mechanisms and
green investments, promoting the
creation of alternatives to the use
of taxed products and activities.
To ensure the credibility and coher-
ence of environmental taxation:
• Audit recommendation 9:
Link
environmental taxation with envi-
ronmental policy as a whole and
ensure in particular that alterna-
tives favourable to the ecological
transition are developed (research,
innovation, investment, etc.);
• Audit recommendation 10:
Set
objectives for changes in environ-
mental taxation within a predictable
and credible trajectory;
• Audit recommendation 11:
Ensure
consistency
between
environ-
mental tax measures and other
compulsory levies.
To level the environmental playing
field in a globalised economy:
• Audit recommendation 12:
support,
at a European level, negotiations on
energy taxation and the creation of
a border adjustment mechanism.
23
Summary - Council of Mandatory Contributions
Conclusion
While the outcome of the pan-
demic is still uncertain at the
beginning
of
2022,
we
can
already say that the economic
policy challenges will gradually
shift in the near future from the
emergency measures that have
characterised the last two years
to more structural measures
aimed not only at sustaining the
growth potential of the economy,
but also at improving the quality
of growth, making it more inclu-
sive and compatible with the
energy and digital transition.
This report has identified three
main areas of tax policy that
are relevant to the challenges
around exiting the crisis:
- clarifying the redistributive
effects of compulsory levies;
- improving the effectiveness
of innovation taxation for com-
petitiveness and sovereignty;
- fostering consent to energy
taxation.
These three topics are bound to
be among the major tax debates
of the next decade. The audit
recommendations made by the
CPO in this report are intended
to inform these choices without
encroaching
on
the
political
arena. Indeed, taxation is, through
and through, the place where
policy choices are made: these
concern the desirable level of
public
revenue
and
expendi-
ture, the nature of the incentives
to address to households and
businesses, and the level of
redistribution implemented by
budgets. While it is not the CPO's
role to give a verdict on these
choices, it does have the mission
of identifying the most effective
instruments for achieving cer-
tain objectives and of pointing
out certain clearly ineffective
measures.
Informing the debate on compul-
sory levies in the medium to long
term, as the CPO is mandated to
do, also involves reiterating some
fundamental principles of good
fiscal governance. Therefore:
-
the
analysis
of
compul-
sory levies cannot take place
without taking into account the
expenditure they finance;
- the different types of levies
should have a clearly stated
main objective, against which
their results should be assessed;
- tax expenditure should be
regularly assessed and, most
importantly,
the
results
of
these assessments should be
acted upon;
24
Summary - Council of Mandatory Contributions
-
in this
post-crisis
period,
where
government
finances
will continue to be under pres-
sure for a long time to come
and taxes will remain at a high
level, it is more important than
ever to be concerned about the
quality of tax acceptance;
- lastly, predictability remains
an essential quality of any
tax policy. In this respect, the
practice at work in France,
which results in a high degree
of instability in the tax stand-
ard, appears less favourable
than that of many of its part-
ners, particularly those whose
institutional practice subjects
major tax reforms to negoti-
ations conducted as part of
coalition
agreements
that
enable households and busi-
nesses to anticipate upcoming
changes in tax rules during
a legislature.
It is therefore important to make
tax consent the fundamental
value of the social contract,
while
firmly
defending
our
fundamental economic interests
in European and international
negotiations.